The United States v. Paramount and How Movie Theater Concessions Got So Expensive
In 1948, the Supreme Court ended the stranglehold Hollywood studios and distributors had on the U.S. movie market. Declaring the big eight a monopoly and ordering them to divest of their ownership of movie theaters and cease other non-competitive practices, with U.S. v. Paramount Pictures, et al., the Court opened the movie industry to independent producers and theaters, and indelibly changed the way we see films (and the films we see).
Prior to the government’s efforts to break their trust, a handful of Hollywood studios and distributors controlled nearly all of the movie theaters in the United States, either through direct or indirect ownership, or by the system of “block booking.” With this latter, the big boys insisted that independent theaters contract to run a “block” of films (some set number). Between controlling the distribution and exhibition, and its strong-arm negotiating, these few companies decided not only where and when any movie would be shown, but set admission prices, as well.
Clearly anti-competitive, beginning in 1928 Uncle Sam sought to limit the studios’ power. Identified by the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) as having a monopoly over 98% of domestic movie distribution, the Justice Department brought suit in 1929 against Paramount-Famous-Lasky Corporation, First National Pictures, Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer, Universal, United Artists, Fox, Pathé Exchange, FBO Pictures, Vitagraph and Educational Film Exchanges (together the Motion Picture Producers and Distributors of America or MPPDA). Declared a trust in the lower courts, the Supreme Court affirmed the decision on November 25, 1930.
But, since the country was in the mire of the Great Depression, that decision was never enforced, and, rather, in 1933, under the protection of the National Industrial Recovery Act, the studios and the government agreed that the former could continue with business as usual. That is, they continued to own and control movie distribution (and block booking continued, as well).
Nonetheless, as the economy improved, the government decided to limit the big studios’ grip on distribution, and in July 1938, filed another suit, this time against seven studios (Paramount, Loew’s, RKO, Warner Bros., 20th Century Fox, Columbia and Universal) and one major distributor (United Artists). The trial was halted only two weeks after it began, and on November 20, 1940, the parties reached a compromise that allowed the studios to keep ownership of theaters, but inhibited block booking.
This angered independent movie producers, including Charlie Chaplin, Samuel Goldwyn, Mary Pickford, Orson Welles, David O. Selznick and Walt Disney, and together, they formed the Society of Independent Motion Picture Producers (SIMPP) to fight the consent decree. Effective, eventually the antitrust suit returned to federal court, and on December 31, 1946, the district court of New York found the defendants in violation of anti-trust laws. It then ordered that bidding had to be competitive and movies were to be licensed individually, as well as prohibited admission price fixing, block-licensing of copywritten movies, and joint ownership of theaters by distributors and exhibitors, among other things.
The parties returned to the Supreme Court, and on May 3, 1948, it entered its decision. The high court agreed with the district court on most points, including affirming the prohibition against price-fixing, joint ownership, major franchises and block licensing; however, the court reversed and remanded on the issue of competitive bidding, noting:
The system would be apt to require as close a supervision as a continuous receivership . . . . The judiciary is unsuited to affairs of business management and control through the power of contempt is crude and clumsy.[1]
This Supreme Court decision still controls movie distribution and exhibition in the U.S., and today, studios split gross profits with theaters. But how they do it is pretty interesting.
During the first few weeks of a movie’s run, the studio receives the bulk of gross ticket sales. While the details vary based on deals between the theaters and the distributors, it’s quite common for the theater to fork over 90%-95% of the revenue from the film on week one, perhaps 80% on week two, etc. By the end of the movie’s run, when the fewest people are going to see a film, the theater is taking in the lion’s share of the gross. When averaging the whole run, the theater might only get 20%-30% of the gross ticket sales, with these numbers varying a bit based on a variety of factors.
As one commentator has noted, this system provides a strong incentive for the studios to make “movies with built-in demand – in the form of a superhero in the lead or a plot drawn from a hit book – and the potential to open with a bang.”
Over time, this has developed such that it’s not uncommon today for theaters to take a loss for a given movie based on ticket sales alone, particularly movies from major studios. There’s really little the theaters can do about this, however, as they have extremely limited leverage in negotiations (particularly for small theater chains). They can’t make the movies themselves, and certainly can’t turn away major blockbusters, lest people stop going to their theater(s). In addition, if a given small theater chain is dealing with a major movie studio, the studio may also say something like, “Well, if you don’t put this movie on 1/4 of your screens for this amount of time and give us X% of the gross, you’ll not be seeing any more Warner Bros. films offered to your theaters.” Major theater chains have a little more leverage in these negotiations, particularly when dealing with smaller studios, but still not that much in general.
What this all means is that the theater must find other ways to make money outside of ticket sales. The solution is to charge ridiculous prices for concessions, which nonetheless is necessary for them to stay in business at all, at least given the way things are done today. (The concession hike began in earnest around the 1970s.) For reference, even with the exorbitantly high prices on food items, only about 4% of a theater’s gross revenue in a given year is profit, despite typically around an 85% profit margin on concession sales themselves, according to Australian market research company IBISWorld.
So, as 55 year veteran of the movie theater business Jack Oberleitner observed, theaters have “left the movie business and [are] now in the popcorn business.”
On the other side, big movies cost pretty amazing sums to produce, and when they flop, that means huge losses for movie studios, despite the favorable terms they get with theaters. Since many feel this is a direct consequence of the prohibition of studio ownership of theaters, they are calling for a change in the law. One of the many arguments they make is claiming ending the prohibition would have the benefit of allowing studios to target releases geographically to better place movies in more favorable markets, and broaden the types of movies they make. As an example, they point to Magic Mike which “hugely overperformed” in St. Louis, Nashville and Kansas City, but had disappointing sales in New York and L.A. If the studios owned the theaters, they would have shortened Magic Mike’s runs on the coast, and perhaps shown it more in the Midwest; thereby, suffering fewer losses, earning greater profit, and giving people more of what they actually want.
Another potential benefit of studio ownership of movie theaters is that it would shorten the time it takes a stale film to move from theaters to home release. As one industry insider noted: “If 92 percent of the gross of a movie comes in the first four weeks, wouldn’t it make sense for [a studio] to put out a movie and say, after four weeks, ‘We’re moving this to DVD?'”
Beyond that, studios would have some small incentive to lower the price of concessions in order to increase the number of people coming to the theaters, and thus increase ticket sales and hype for their movies. If Disney owned theaters saw higher volumes of ticket sales for their movies, and ticket prices were reasonably close between studios, Disney movies would consistently be topping the box office charts. Under the current system, theaters really have little incentive to focus on overall volume of customers, instead trying to focus on the right customers- ones that not only buy tickets, but also are willing to pay the high prices for concessions.
Of course, with the few potential benefits of allowing studios to own theaters again comes potential drawbacks, many of which were seen before U.S. v. Paramount Pictures, et al.
If you liked this article, you might also enjoy our new popular podcast, The BrainFood Show (iTunes, Spotify, Google Play Music, Feed), as well as:
- Why Short Movie Advertisement Clips are Called “Trailers”
- The Color of the Background Preceding Movie Trailers Actually Means Something
- A Brief History of Taxes in the U.S. & Why They are Due on April 15th
- Why the Monopoly Player Pieces (Thimble, Top Hat, Etc.) are What They Are
- Why Popcorn Pops
- The Famous Players-Lasky Antitrust Case
- A Proposal for Fixing the Box Office Problem
- Time to Let Studios Own Theaters
- The U.S. Declares Hollywood Guilty of Antitrust Conspiracy
- U.S. Supreme Court decides Paramount antitrust case
- United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc.
- United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc. et al.
- Why Does Popcorn at Movies Cost So Much
- How Movie Distribution Works
Notes
[1] United States v. Paramount Pictures, et al., 334 U.S. 131, 163 (1948)Share the Knowledge! |
One area where theaters are trying to increase profits is through diversification of events. They now host live concerts and such. What would be ironic is if the studios one day find themselves forced to negotiate for time slots, concede lower ticket sales receipt share, etc.
Wouldn’t a more direct and effective solution to the problem be to force studios to offer theaters fair contracts rather than strong arming them into deals through which they can’t possibly make a profit? I’ve know about the theaters taking a loss on tickets forever and I’ve always thought it a horrible deed on behalf of the studios. They could easily make a profit while still letting theaters keep 25-50% of the ticket sales. The fact that they take 95% of the ticket sales is pure greed.
“…block-licensing of copywritten movies…” There is no such word as “copywritten,” the closest similar word is “copywriting,” the act of writing advertising copy. Perhaps you meant “copyrighted”?
Wonder if they have a set price they are to charge? I wonder would would happen if I only charged a dollar a head on admission and then gave the studio 95 cents per head? I wonder why the major theater companies don’t threaten that?
Some do offer lower prices for matinees, etc. I suspect the studios would simply threaten to withhold offerings to those chains if they pulled something like that. It would be a losing proposition for everyone, of course, but money still talks.
Screw Hollywood and their ant-America attitude. Last movie I payed for was Saving Private Ryan. Any movie I watched in the past decade has been streamed from sharing sites with no money going to Hollywierd. Wouldn’t matter a bit if they went belly up and in fact I’d like for it to happen.
Amen
The Big Studios rarely lose money as they sell rights to the movies before they are even made. There are many distribution channels which they get funding for the movie – theatres, pay for view, cable, netflix, broadcasters, airlines, dvds, tax shelters, etc. All the distribution channels have to fork over money before the movie is complete. That way the studio gets to spread the risk around and avoids putting its own money into a picture. When a movie flops, the Studio doesn’t take bath on the production costs since what they put in is a small percentage. The Box Office gross is a nice scorecard but it doesn’t tell much about how much a Studio made.
As I write this it’s over 7 years after the original article was written…I wonder how streaming, Covid, and such have affected all of this.